Trade, poverty and inequality
This page in:

What key insights have emerged from development economics in the past decade, and how should they impact the work of the World Bank? A new working paper Toward Successful Development Policies: Insights from Research in Development Economics from the Bank’s research department captures 13 of the most significant insights in the world of development economics.
Here’s insight #13 – on what we have learned from recent research on the size of the welfare gains from trade.See all previous insights here: Thirteen insights for successful development policies
International integration accelerates growth and reduces poverty when it is supported with strong institutions, rule of law, and investment.ref1 Historically, episodes of rapid growth are associated with increasing international integration and trade. Many East Asian economies, such as Japan, the Republic of Korea and China have managed to attain remarkable growth rates while integrating into the global economy. Conversely, many slow growing regions are left out of the globalization process.
ref2 To accurately quantify the gains from trade it is also necessary to account for the structure of global value chains, input-output linkages, knowledge spillovers, pro-competitive effects, and other mechanisms that may amplify them. In addition, trade may create dynamic gains which can be sizable. A recent study of the impact of WTO accession on patenting, for example, finds that about 7 percent of the increase in knowledge creation during the 1990s can be attributed to trade policy reforms.ref3 Notwithstanding these challenges, studies that exploit quasi-experimental variation in trade costs generated by shocks as varied as the closing of the Suez Canal,ref4 the reunification of Germany,ref5 oil price fluctuations,ref6 and major infrastructure expansionsref7 consistently show that reducing trade costs improves incomes on average.
Separating the impact of trade from other developments that overlap with episodes of increasing globalization, such as technological progress, is challenging.Although globalization has been a force for development for the last three decades, protectionism is now on the rise. One reason is the frustration of those whom trade may have left permanently behind. International trade is not a zero-sum game, as it increases the size of the pie. However, it also changes how the pie is divided, creating winners and losers. The losses often are highly visibly concentrated among specific people in specific areas. The gains, by contrast, are often widely spread and therefore less salient. This undermines political support for global integration.
ref8 yielding several novel insights:
,- ref9 These negative localized effects persist in the long run, and the affected regions take a long time to recover, if at all.ref10 Since workers’ regions seem as important as their industries and occupations in determining the distributional impacts of globalization, it is crucial to switch from industry-based social protection policies to more flexible and possibly region-based policies.ref11 The emergence of China as a dominant economic power and its integration into the global trading system have caused regions in both developed and developing countries with a high concentration of import competing industries to fall behind other regions. Workers who are adversely affected by trade liberalization face high moving costs and are often not able to leave to find better jobs in other regions. The adverse effects of trade liberalization are consequently concentrated in particular regions, while the benefits are widespread throughout the whole economy.
- ref12 The consumption gains resulting from lower prices tend to be widely distributed (as most people consume many different products), but job losses in import-competing sectors tend to be highly concentrated (as most people usually only have one job – which if lost to import competition is a major shock).ref13 .
- ref14 Similarly, firms in India increased their markups after trade was liberalized, thereby offsetting some of the gains for consumers.ref15 .
. These include reducing intranational trade costs in developing countries by investing in infrastructure, connectivity and market access, and setting up flexible social protection systems. Better infrastructure allows domestic and export market access for poor households, thereby facilitating structural transformation from subsistence farming to cash crops. Improved connectivity and platforms allow small enterprises, which tend to employ more low-skill and informal workers than large firms, to compete in global markets. Flexible social protection and investment schemes can help protect workers and entrepreneurs in lagging regions, whereas industry-based protection systems are often unsuccessful, since they fail to target groups that are suffering localized knock-on effects arising because of adjustment costs and limits to their mobility.